2.
Forced Collectivization The
forced collectivization of agriculture from 1929 to 1933 was an integral part
of the Stalin revolution. His argument
in favor of it was simple: an economy divided against itself cannot stand-planned
industrial mobilization was incompatible with small-scale
private agriculture in the traditional manner.
Collectivization meant combining many small peasant holdings into a single large
unit run in theory by the peasants (now called collective farmers), but in
practice by the collective farm chairman guided
by the government's Five Year Plan. Joseph
Stalin LIQUIDATION
OF THE KULAKS Collectivization,
not surprisingly, met with fierce resistance, especially from the
more successful peasants called kulaks, who were averse
to surrendering their private plots and their freedom in running their
households. Their resistance therefore had to be broken,
and the Communist party fomented a rural class-struggle,
seeking help from the poorer peasants. Sometimes, however,
even the poorest peasants sided with the
local kulaks. Under these conditions, Stalin did
not shrink from unleashing violence in
the countryside aimed at the “liquidation of
the kulaks as a class." For Stalin the collectivization drive
meant an all-out war on what was for him
the citadel of backwardness: the peasant tradition and rebelliousness so
prominent under the tsars. The following
reading- Stalin's address to the Conference of
Marxist Students of the Agrarian
Question, December 1929-conveys his intentions. It is a good example of
Stalin's rhetoric; he drives home his point by continually restating his
argument. The
characteristic feature of our work during the
past year is: (a) that we, the party and the Soviet
government, have developed an offensive on the whole
front against the capitalist elements in the countryside;
and (b) that this offensive, as you know, has brought
about and is bringing about very palpable, positive
results. What
does this mean? It means that we have passed from the
policy of restricting the exploiting
proclivities of the kulaks to the policy of eliminating
the kulaks as a class. This means
that we have made, and are still making,
one of the most decisive turns in our
whole policy…. Could we have undertaken such an
offensive against the kulaks five years
or three years ago? Could we then have counted
on success in such an offensive? No, we
could not. That would have been the most
dangerous adventurism! That would
have been playing a very dangerous game at
offensive. We would certainly have come to grief
and, once we had come to grief, we would have
strengthened the position of the
kulaks. Why? Because we
did not yet have strongholds in the rural
districts in the shape
of a wide network of state farms and
collective farms upon which to rely in a determined offensive against
the kulaks. Because at that time we were not yet able to substitute
for the capitalist production of the
kulaks’ socialist production in the shape of
the collective farms and state farms .... But
today? What is the position? Today,
we have an adequate material base which enables us to strike at
the kulaks ,
to break their resistance,
to eliminate them as a class , and to substitute
for their output the output of the
collective farms and state farms…. Now,
as you see, we have the material base
which enables us to substitute for
kulak output the output of the collective
farms and state farms. That is why our offensive against the
kulaks is now meeting with undeniable
success. That is how the offensive against the kulaks must be carried on, if we mean a
real offensive and not futile declamations against
the kulaks. That
is why we have recently passed from the policy
of restricting
the exploiting proclivities
of the kulaks to the policy of eliminating
the kulaks
as a class.... Now we
are able to carry on a determined offensive against
the kulaks, to break their resistance, to
eliminate them as a class and substitute for their
output the output of the collective
farms and state farms. Now, the kulaks are
being expropriated by the masses of poor and middle peasants
themselves, by the masses
who are putting solid collectivization into
practice. Now the expropriation of
the kulaks in the regions of solid collectivization
is no longer just an administrative
measure. Now, the expropriation
of the kulaks is an integral part of the formation
and development of the
collective farms.... ...
[Should] the kulak ... be permitted to join
the collective farm? Of course not, for he
is a sworn enemy of the
collective farm movement. Clear, one
would think. |