The hierarchy of
the old school of politics begins with the king and ends on
the gallows.
When the workingmen of Lyons arose, saying, give us bread
or kill us . . . [a]s it seemed too difficult to support
them, we strangled them.
By this means order was reestablished. . . .
I ask, who really is interested in the maintenance of the
economic conditions of today? No one at all. . . .
To every poor person who is pale from hunger there is a
rich one who grows pale from fear. . . .
If a thing is true philosophically is it any less true
economically? . . . [F]or society there is neither a partial
progress nor a partial decline. The whole society
rises, or falls. When justice is exercised, all have
the advantage, when right is obscured, the whole
suffers. A people in which one class is suppressed resembles
a man who has a wounded leg. The injured leg prevents him
from using the good one. This sounds paradoxical, [but] the
oppressor and the oppressed gain equally by the removal of
oppression; they lose equally by its maintenance. . . . The
bourgeoisie has built its sovereignty upon free
competition--the basis of tyranny . . . !
. . . [F]rom individualism springs competition; from
competition, fluctuation of wages and their insufficiency.
Having reached this point, we come upon . . . the breaking
of the family ties. Every marriage creates increasing
expense. . . . Children are born to the poor, how shall they
be fed? . . . [W]e find so many of these unfortunate little
creatures dead in dark corners, on the stairs of lonely
churches, even in the vestibules of the buildings where laws
are made. . . . The greatest evil is always found where
industry has chosen its field of action. Ought not the state
step forth and tell the poor mother: --I will take care of
your children. . . . No, it ought to go further, it ought to
take away the reason. . . .
...
To arrive at a social revolution it is necessary to takes
its starting point in the conditions of present society. In
other words, that which is important for us to find, is not
so much a mathematical formula, as a practical solution.
Robert Owen was not a practical reformer, because he
wanted to base the distribution of the products of labor on
the needs of a society and not upon the services rendered.
The Saint-Simonists have not had any practical reformers
because they have demanded the abolition of the family and
the consequent destruction of the principle of inheritance.
Charles Fourier was not a practical reformer, because he
laid the distribution of all labor, industrial or
agricultural, at the mercy of the individual preference and
because he has taken up everything in his social
organization, except the idea of efficiency.
But what mighty ideas stir in all these works, especially
in those of Fourier. . . .
The government ought to be considered as the supreme
regulator of production and endowed for this duty with great
power.
This task would consist of fighting competition and of
finally overcoming it.
The government ought to float a loan with the proceeds of
which it should erect social workshops in the most
important branches of national industry. . . .
As the false and anti-social education given to the
present generation does not allow them to look farther for .
. . recompense than a motive of emulation and encouragement,
the difference in wages ought to be based on the scale of
work done; an entirely new form of education in this respect
would completely change the [current] ideas and customs. . .
. [W]ages, in all cases, must be sufficient for the
subsistence of the workman.
. . . [A]]fter having killed competition among
individuals, it would be absurd to let it subsist among
corporations. Therefore, in each sphere of work, a central
workshop must be established, to which all others would be
in the position of supplementary workshops. . . .
In a system where every sphere of industry would gather
together a certain number of men animated by the same
spirit, acting under the same impulse, having common hopes,
common interests, where would be the place, I ask you, for
these adulterations of products, these cowardly subterfuges,
these daily lies, these subtle frauds which to-day compel
each producer, every merchant, cost what it may, to take
away from his neighbor his customers and his fortune?
Industrial reform would . . . mean a profound moral
revolution and would bring about in one day more . . . than
all sermons of preachers and all speeches of moralists could
in a century. . . .
An economic revolution must be attempted:
1- Because the present social conditions are too full of
misery, inequity and turpitude, to last much longer.
2- Because everybody, irrespective of position, rank or
fortune, is interested in the creation of a new social
order.
3- Finally because it is possible, even easy, to produce
this necessary revolution in a peaceful way.
In the new world into which we could enter, some things,
perhaps, must be accomplished for the complete realization
of the principle of fraternity. But at least all would be
prepared for this realization, which would be the work of
education. Humanity has been too far separated from its goal
to reach it in one day. The corrupt civilization, under the
yoke of which we still groan, has disturbed all interests,
but at the same time it has lost all reason and has poisoned
all springs of human intelligence. Iniquity has taken the
place of justice, falsehood has become truth and men tear
each other to pieces under the protection of darkness.
Many false ideas must be destroyed; doubtlessly we can
count upon their disappearing. The day will come, when we
will acknowledge that he, whom God has endowed with more
strength, or greater intelligence, must do more for his
fellow men. Then let genius, and it is fully worthy of it,
exercise its legitimate power, not by the means of the
tribute which it levies upon society, but by the grandeur of
the services which it will render to society. For the
inequality of capabilities has for its goal, not the
inequalities of rights, but the inequalities of duties.
|